Equivalent Optimal Matchings Produced by the Priority Mechanism

I provide propositions relating the structure of the compatibility graph and the number of maximal matchings produced by the priority mechanism.

The priority mechanism introduced in (Roth et al., 2005) may produce many maximal matchings depending on the structure of the compatibility graph. In this article, I show that there are two maximal matchings for some priority ordering if there is a 4-cycle in the compatibility graph. Further, if the compatibility graph induces a complete subgraph, then the number of maximal matchings for patients involved in that subgraph can be computed by evaluating a double factorial.

Model of Matching Pairs of Patients with Priorities

There are nn number of patients contained in the set N={1,,n}N=\{1, \ldots, n\}. Pairs i,ji, j are mutually compatible if jj has a compatible donor for the patient of ii and ii has a compatible donor for the patient of jj, that is, kjKik_j \in K_i and kiKjk_i \in K_j. A mutual compatibility matrix R=[ri,j]iN,jNR=\left[r_{i, j}\right]_{i \in N, j \in N} is defined as for any i,jNi, j \in N,

ri,j={1 if i and j are mutually compatible 0 otherwise . r_{i, j}=\left\{\begin{array}{ll}1 & \text { if } i \text { and } j \text { are mutually compatible } \\ 0 & \text { otherwise }\end{array}.\right.

A compatibility graph consisting of mutually compatible patients can be defined as G=(N,E)G=(N, E) where EE is the set of edges connecting mutually compatible patients.

A matching of patients μ\mu is a set that contains pairs of mutually compatible patients that are matched with one another and patients matched with themselves. Patient piNp_i \in N is matched with patient pjNp_j \in N in the matching μ\mu if and only if μ={pipj}\mu=\left\{p_i p_j\right\}. In this model, cycles of matched patients are not considered. Hence, it cannot be the case that μ={pipjpk}\mu=\left\{p_i p_j p_k\right\} for some pi,pj,pkNp_i, p_j, p_k \in N. Note that a matching can contain multiple elements, and patients who are matched with one another are of the form pipip_i p_i (e.g. μ={p1p2,p3p4,p5p5}\mu=\left\{p_1 p_2, p_3 p_4, p_5 p_5\right\}). A patient is matched with themselves only if he cannot be matched with any others. A priority ordering (p1,,pn)\left(p_1, \ldots, p_n\right) among the patients orders each patient pip_i from 1 being the highest priority to nn being the lowest. Each patient has a distinct integer representing their priority.

As described in (Roth et al., 2005), there is a manager who is given a priority ordering p=(p1,,pn)p=\left(p_1, \ldots, p_n\right) and wishes to find the set of exchanges that maximizes a preference relation p\succ_p defined over matchings. The preference relation p\succ_p is defined as for any matching μ\mu and v,μpvv, \mu \succ_p v if and only if whenever matchings μ\mu and vv differ in only one patient, the matching with the higher priority patient is preferred, and adding additional matched patients to an existing matching always results in a preferred matching. Given a priority ordering, μ\mu is a maximal matching if μpv\mu \succ_p v for all other matchings vv.

The goal of this article is to quantify and characterize maximal matchings. Hence, given a priority ordering pp, matching μpv\mu \sim_p v (i.e. matching μ\mu is equivalent to vv) if and only if for all matchings mm \neq μ\mu and mv,μpmm \neq v, \mu \succ_p m and vpmv \succ_p m. The set of maximal and equivalent matchings is contained in the equivalence class [μ]p:={v[\mu]_p:=\left\{v\right. is a maximal matching vpμ}\left.\mid v \sim_p \mu\right\}. Roth showed that the greedy algorithm in the form of the priority algorithm produces these maximal matchings. See my previous post for more details on the priority mechanism.

To understand the relationship between maximal matchings and priority orderings, I define an important concept from graph theory. A 4-cycle in the graph G=(V,E)G=(V, E) is a set of vertices {v1,,v4}V\left\{v_1, \ldots, v_4\right\} \subseteq V such that vivjv_i \neq v_j for all i,j{1,,4}i, j \in\{1, \ldots, 4\} and {v1,v2},{v2,v3},{v3,v4}\left\{v_1, v_2\right\},\left\{v_2, v_3\right\},\left\{v_3, v_4\right\}, and {v4,v1}\left\{v_4, v_1\right\} are its edges contained in EE.

Analysis of Maximal Matchings in the Priority Mechanism

In this section, I present the relationship between the structure of the compatibility graph and maximal matchings. The priority algorithm may produce many maximal matchings. Hence, given the structure of the compatibility graph, I provide propositions relating this structure and maximal matchings.

Proposition.\textbf{Proposition.}
If an induced subgraph of the compatibility graph GG contains a 4-cycle, then there is a priority ordering pp such that patients in the cycle can be matched in μ\mu and vv and, further, μpv\mu \sim_p v.

Proof\textit{Proof}. Suppose a generated subgraph of GG contains a 4-cycle. Let p1,,p4p_1, \ldots, p_4 be the patients in the cycle. Hence, this implies that p1p_1 is adjacent to p4p_4 and p2,pip_2, p_i is adjacent to pi1p_{i-1} and pi+1p_{i+1} for i=2,3i=2,3, and p4p_4 is adjacent to p1p_1 and p3p_3. Let p5,,pnp_5, \ldots, p_n be the other patients. Consider the priority ordering p=(p1,,p4,p5,pn)p=\left(p_1, \ldots, p_4, p_5 \ldots, p_n\right). Then {p1p2,p3p4}\left\{p_1 p_2, p_3 p_4\right\} and {p1p4,p3p2}\left\{p_1 p_4, p_3 p_2\right\} will always be two optimal matchings such that {p1p2,p3p4}p{p1p4,p3p2}\left\{p_1 p_2, p_3 p_4\right\} \sim_p\left\{p_1 p_4, p_3 p_2\right\}.

Proposition.\textbf{Proposition.}
For every induced, simple, complete subgraph of the compatibility graph GG with i4i \geq 4 vertices, there exists a priority ordering pp such that for the equivalence class of maximal matchings, [μ]p[\mu]_p,

[μ]p={(i1)!! if i is even (i2)!! if i is odd  \left|[\mu]_p\right|=\left\{\begin{array}{c} (i-1)!!\text { if } i \text { is even } \\ (i-2)!!\text { if } i \text { is odd } \end{array}\right.

where n!!n!! is the double factorial of nn (i.e. n!!=n(n2)(n4)(3)(1)n!!=n(n-2)(n-4) \ldots(3)(1) for odd nn).

Proof\textit{Proof}. Let the induced complete subgraph of the compatibility graph GG with i4i \geq 4 vertices be denoted as KiK_i. Since KiK_i is complete, a maximal matching requires that ii patients are matched if ii is even and i1i-1 patients are matched if ii is odd. Hence, if ii is even, then select any priority ordering such that q=(p1,,pi,,pn)q=\left(p_1, \ldots, p_i, \ldots, p_n\right) where p1,,pip_1, \ldots, p_i are the ii patients and pi+1,,pnp_{i+1}, \ldots, p_n are the others. By the number of perfect matchings of a complete graph theorem, [μ]q=(i1)!!\left|[\mu]_q\right|=(i-1)!!. Similarly, if ii is odd, then consider the priority ordering w=(p1,,pi1,pi,,pn)w=\left(p_1, \ldots, p_{i-1}, p_i, \ldots, p_n\right) where p1,,pi1p_1, \ldots, p_{i-1} are the i1i-1 matched patients, pip_i is not matched, and pi+1,,pnp_{i+1}, \ldots, p_n are the others. By the same theorem, the number of perfect matchings among p1,,pi1p_1, \ldots, p_{i-1} is [μ]w=(i2)!!\left|[\mu]_w\right|=(i-2)!!.

References

  1. Roth, A. E., Sönmez, T., & Ünver, M. U. (2005). Pairwise kidney exchange. Journal of Economic Theory, 125(2), 151–188.